January 7, 2004
Leading Horses to Water
Lately Ive
been wrestling with two complicated experiences, things I wanted to write about
in this space, but felt inhibited about exploring fully. So my language here
will be a bit oblique. What is spurring me to write is first, a disappointing
experience with a grant I was hoping to get, and second, ambivalent feelings
I have about a government-funded educational project that I have an institutional
connection to.
What I'm concerned
about is the nature of incentive in academic life. Many of academias critics
regard this question as the greatest specific damage that the tenure system
inflicts on higher education, that the lack of a risk-reward calculus post-tenure
gives few scholars the incentive to excel, and punishes few for the failure
to do so. This isnt quite the way I want to come at the problemfor
one, I think it involves a highly questionable assumption that such incentives
meaningfully and typically exist in business or other institutions, and are
the main engine for creativity and innovationbut I recognize the importance
of the general issue.
How can any given
institution articulate a set of preferences or desires for particular kinds
of scholarship, teaching or activity from its faculty, and do you need rewards
or incentives to get otherwise independently-minded faculty to respond to those
desires? What makes academics change course to pursue a particular kind of reward?
Theres an
obvious bookend to this question, and thats whether there are any meaningful
sticks at all to go alongside the carrots, but thats a matter for another
essay, and more directly involves some of the problems with tenure.
Heres my
list of meaningful institutional incentives that I can think of, ranked roughly
in the order of their importance to the average tenured faculty member (obtaining
tenure being an almost separate class of initial incentive):
1. Secure, reliable, long-term commitment to funding sabbatical leaves for an individual faculty member
2. Significant permanent salary increases
3. Structurally permanent course releases
4. Short-term course releases
5. Short-term programmatic stipends
6. Permanent relief from some or all service and administrative work unconnected to the facultys personal interests or objectives
7. Significant autonomous control over a dedicated, personally customized institutional unit or resource (major research project, institute, department, etcetera)
8. Personalized endorsement or warm acknowledgement of a faculty members research or pedagogical projects by top administrators
9. A strong degree of privileged access to administrative decision-making for an individual faculty member
10. Generalized administrative endorsement of an overall position or faction to which a faculty member subscribes within the institution
11. Committed, differentialized administrative and collegial non-interference in an individual faculty members perception of his or her own pedagogical, scholarly and administrative domains
12. Generalized support for faculty as a whole in grant-seeking efforts
Theres some
more general atmospheric incentives I could describe, but faculty
are often not aware of them as incentive until the atmosphere or culture shifts
negatively for some reason. There is also a class of incentive that can be powerfully
motivating that mostly lies outside of any single institution, most crucially
seeking reputation capital through scholarly production within a specialized
field or discipline, publishing textbooks or other works for profit, and seeking
credibility and circulation within the wider public sphere. Institutions can
decide to help faculty seek those rewards with sabbaticals, salary replacement
and so on, but not much more than that.
Not all of these
incentives are equally motivating to all faculty. When I recently helped put
together a faculty seminar here, I was actually struck at how the offer of a
course release was a powerful disincentive for some of the faculty that were
attractive potential participants. Nor can they be found at all institutions.
Swarthmore, for example, does not give a significant raise at promotion to associate
or full professor (the title is largely honorary) and we give relatively minimal
merit-based raises. Most smaller undergraduate institutions avoid giving structurally
permanent course releases or structured relief from administrative or service
responsibilities, unlike large research universities, where such incentives
are often part of the package used to woo especially desirable senior scholars.
Some of the intangibles are sometimes the strongest rewards for certain people:
I know that getting some sense that Swarthmore officially shares my belief that
a generalist and interdisciplinary approach to faculty development is more in
line with our institutional values than continued narrow specialization would
be a more desirable reward and more motivating to me than more money.
In any event, most
of these incentives are generally designated rewards for individual productivity
and achievement, and often work in concert with disciplinary or public rewards
for scholarly achievement or general reputation. They are rarely used to reform
pedagogy or academic administration, to encourage academics to study one subject
more or another subject less, to achieve any more targeted institutional or
social goal.
In this case, the
only incentives that matter are internal and external grants and funding that
are differentially targeted at particular kinds of research or institutional
reforms, or some kind of highly focused top-down advocacy and support from the
top reaches of academic administration in a particular institution.
If an external
agency or internal administration actually wants to change academia in some
particular fashion, even if it merely to encourage the study of some new discipline,
or endorse one approach over another, they have to think very carefully about
how to proceed. These kinds of incentives, properly designed, really can have
a major impact, but it is very easy for them to be diverted, co-opted or ignored
if theyre not actively looked after by the people who set them in motion,
if theyre not very precisely defined and targeted at the outset, or if
theyre paired alongside an incentive that pulls in another, contradictory
direction.
In the work Ive
done with several foundations giving academic grants, Ive been impressed
with the extent to which they have been very clear about the specific kinds
of things they wanted to reward, which went well beyond simple excellence.
(Say, for example, wanting to diversify the pool of institutions receiving support
for their doctoral students, and to widen the range of disciplines being rewarded).
To stay on target takes not just precise standards but also constant monitoring
and intervention by the grant giver. If you want to reward some particular kind
of behavior or choice among academics, you have to build in some kind of evaluative
weighting when making your choices, and aggressively shepherd decisions so that
weighting is always taken into account.
In the case of
my own disappointing experience, I applied with a collaborator from the sciences
for a grant that I understood was supposed to reward collaborations across disciplinesbut
essentially each one of us were evaluated separately, as if we were two unrelated
people who each had to excel above the competition in isolation from each other.
If you dont build in a weighted reward for applying as interdisciplinary
collaborators, so that all non-collaborative projects are at a structurally
inflexible disadvantage no matter how excellent they might be, youre actually
discouraging collaborative applicant. It makes it two times as hard to be selected:
your project has to pass muster twice, and is subject to twice the possible
political and institutional vagaries in that judgement. It's hard to reflect
on a grant you didn't get without descending into sour grapes--you always have
to take seriously the possibility that your proposal was flawed, and you also
have to know, if you've been a part of making decisions about grants, that the
decision often comes down to very small, fractional differences between generally
excellent applicants. But I definitely walked away from this one feeling this
case revealed a problem with how some grant-givers actually look after the goals
they have set.
On the other hand,
you can look after those goals too aggressively or inflexibly. In the case of
the federal project Im involved with, its clear what the grant-givers
would like to encourage, but theyre so rigid in their approach (because
of statutory limitations and a mass of their own home-grown bureaucratic regulations),
most of the things theyd like to see come to pass will either not happen
because they entail considerable extra make-work for participating
faculty or because they are non-adaptive to particular institutional cultures.
So theres a disincentive to respond to this intended incentive, making
it stillborn. (One suspects this is fairly common with a lot of federal grants.)
I think it is very
possible for foundations, political groups, philanthropists and governments
to shift academic institutions this way or that, to encourage or discourage
particular kinds of research or teaching, and to reasonably hope that there
will be visible general social benefits from these initiative. This can be done
indirectly, through various incentive structures, rather than through crude
statutory restrictions on public universities or other blunt instruments. (Or,
in the case of a reformist college administration, I think its easier
to gently push things in a new direction rather than pursue pogroms and such
in the neo-Stalinist approach favored by John Silber.)
Any institution thinking along these lines is best advised to be precise, be clear and stay heavily involved at every stage of the process of changebecause academic inertia is a powerful, pervasive force, and tends to quietly and without malice subvert well-meaning hands-off forms of benevolence to its own ends, to reinforce the status quo.